The Triumph of Fantasy over Science, Part 1

The Rise of Fantasy as the Basis for Economic Policy

by Rob Dietz

Two competing camps attract people from all over the world. One is Science Camp, and the other is Fantasy Camp.

At Science Camp, the counselors teach campers that we live on a single blue-green planet with finite resources. The curriculum at Science Camp focuses on figuring out how to conserve and share those resources. There’s a strong undercurrent of appreciation (maybe even reverence) for nature and humanity’s place in it — a desire to learn about and safeguard life on this planet.

At Fantasy Camp, the counselors educate campers to believe that humanity can circumvent natural limits. Campers are taught that our unstoppable ingenuity can overcome any resource shortages or manage any amount of waste generation. There’s a strong undercurrent of consumption — a desire to accumulate ever more power and stuff in an attempt to gain complete control over life (and even death).

This division of the world’s people into two camps is a bit crude. After all, some people can’t attend either camp, since they’re engaged in a struggle to get by on the meager resources available to them. Other people are so taken up by their jobs, ideology, or religion that they don’t pay attention to either camp. Still others may be in transit from one camp to another. For example, people learning the ins and outs of climate change, planetary overshoot, biodiversity loss, etc., might begin to disentangle themselves from Fantasy Camp and start leaning toward Science Camp.

Counselors and campers at Science Camp put a lot of stock in observations and facts. Facts like these:

  • When we extract and burn fossil fuels, carbon dioxide accumulates in the atmosphere. A higher concentration of carbon dioxide produces side effects (e.g., increasing temperatures and acidifying oceans) that threaten global climate stability.
  • When we convert forests, grasslands, and wetlands to farms, cities, and suburban sprawl, we decrease the amount of habitat available to non-human species, and we reduce the ecological richness of the landscape.
  • When we extract fish, trees, or other natural resources faster than Mother Nature can replace them, we collapse populations and sometimes cause long-term ecological damage.

Grappling with such facts can lead to clear-headed thinking about limits — recognition that we need to limit the burning of fossil fuels, limit the conversion of natural habitat, and limit the rate of resource extraction. Ecological economists are some of the most clear-thinking enrollees at Science Camp. They approach economic growth and ecological limits with practicality, seeking policies and institutions that enhance human well-being without overwhelming the capacity of planetary life-support systems.

In contrast, the people registered at Fantasy Camp, especially the neoclassical economists, tend to ignore, deny, or dispute facts that conflict with their pre-existing ideas about infinite economic growth. At the same time, they cling to tidbits of conventional wisdom that support their current worldview. Their refusal to incorporate facts into their thinking about how to operate the economy is especially dangerous because it feeds the consumptive frenzy that pushes ecosystems and societies to the brink.

When you compare the foundational principles of ecological economics to those of mainstream/neoclassical economics (see table), it becomes ever clearer that one has a strong basis in reality. The principles of ecological economics stem from the laws of physics and ecology instead of “truthy” assumptions about human behavior and markets. The logic behind ecological economics suggests a different policy path than the theories behind neoclassical economics.

Foundational Principles of Fantasy Camp and Science Camp

Neoclassical Economics (Fantasy Camp) Ecological Economics (Science Camp)
People are rational utility maximizers. They make decisions rationally (at the margin) with the explicit goal of improving their own lives and maximizing their well-being. Sometimes people behave rationally, and other times irrationally. Behavior is influenced by emotion, culture, circumstance, and many factors beyond rational self interest.
People consume goods and services to meet needs. Since meeting needs increases people’s utility (satisfaction with life), more consumption is better. Consuming enough is preferable to continuous pursuit of more, given the diminishing returns of additional consumption and the social and environmental consequences of overconsumption.
The goal for an economy is growth — continuously increasing production and consumption. Growth means more jobs, more consumer utility, more purchasing power. The goal for an economy is optimal scale — the size at which the rising marginal costs of growth equal the diminishing marginal benefits. Growing the economy past this point is counterproductive.
Value is determined by prices in the market. If something of value does not have a price, we should find a way to bring it into the market. Some things that have value are not priced in markets. We need to establish mechanisms beyond the market to recognize this value.

There’s one other big difference between Science Camp and Fantasy Camp. Science Camp draws many fewer supporters than Fantasy Camp. To make a positive economic transition, we need to orchestrate a reversal of this situation, and to do so requires us to address two questions:

  1. Why do so many people pitch their tents in Fantasy Camp?
  2. After decades of failing to attract people to Science Camp, what should we do?

Why People Favor Fantasy

As Bill Rees has noted, “If intelligence and logic were the principal determinants of economic policy, the primary goal would be to ensure that growth slows as we reach the optimal scale and that the economy not exceed this optimal size.” But given the struggle of ecological economics to gain ground on neoclassical economics, we can mostly eliminate “intelligence and logic” as driving forces that motivate people to decide which camp to enter. Indeed, three factors that have little to do with intelligence and logic are behind this.

1. The psychology of inclusion drives people to follow the in-vogue philosophy. Dan Kahan, a legal scholar at Yale University, defines the term “protective cognition” as a sort of automatic defense mechanism that people employ to dismiss scientifically sound evidence that poses a threat to their worldview. Like an immune system fighting off invading viruses, protective cognition works in people’s minds to repel invading facts that would require them to rethink their dearest beliefs. Kahan writes, “Because accepting such [facts] could drive a wedge between them and their peers, they have a strong emotional predisposition to reject it.” With so many people having internalized the concepts of unlimited economic growth and the triumph of technology over nature, protective cognition puts up a formidable obstacle to widespread adoption of ecological economics. It can take years of fact bombardment to begin chipping away at this obstacle.

Fantasy Camp counselors shouldn’t be setting economic policy.

2. Neoclassical economics has become entrenched in the culture. The way people approach daily living and interactions within the economy has become aligned with the neoclassical tenet of self interest (mostly by seeking high-paying jobs and adopting lifestyles of materialism). Neoclassical ideology permeates universities. With so many business and economics students, universities are churning out graduates who buy into the neoclassical approach. The degree of entrenchment came about because neoclassical prescriptions worked at a time when increasing material goods meant increasing well-being. As Herman Daly has pointed out, this was the case when the Earth was relatively empty of people and our stuff. We could extract resources and dump wastes without worrying about running out of supplies (of either inputs or waste absorption capacity). But that logic has become faulty, and even dangerous, as we have filled the planet with ourselves and our things.

3. They spin a real good story over at Fantasy Camp. The message of unending growth is enticing, as long as we disregard the Icarus-like consequences of being seduced by it. This message makes regular appearances in fantasy movies. For example, in The Matrix, Neo (the hero) says, “I’m going to show these people what you don’t want them to see. I’m going to show them… a world without rules and controls, without borders or boundaries, a world where anything is possible.” Although this sort of message belongs in a movie theater, it seems to pop up even more often in the political theater. After Ronald Reagan cruised to Presidential victory over Jimmy Carter (whose message of conservation failed to resonate), he said, “There are no limits to growth and human progress when men and women are free to follow their dreams.” This quote, which makes it seem like Reagan employed Disney’s top talent to write his speeches, is literally set in stone in a Washington, DC monument. Reagan’s message is far more compelling than something like, “Individual freedom is a cornerstone of society, but freedom of choice may be constrained by social and environmental limits to growth. Men and women need to take such constraints into account when deciding which dreams to follow.”

These three factors won’t go away on their own. To increase the prominence of Science Camp, we have to take concerted action. Part 2 will explore how to enroll more people in Science Camp and supplant fantasy as the basis for economic policy.

 

 

 


Rob Dietz brings a fresh perspective to the discussion of economics and environmental sustainability. His diverse background in economics, environmental science and engineering, and conservation biology (plus his work in the public, private, and nonprofit sectors) has given him an unusual ability to connect the dots when it comes to the topic of sustainability. Rob is the author, with Dan O’Neill, of Enough Is Enough: Building a Sustainable Economy in a World of Finite Resources.

 


Print Friendly, PDF & Email
11 replies
  1. John D.
    John D. says:

    Come on, Mr. Dietz! Science Camp just isn’t any fun. I’ve been to these camps and Fantasy Camp has big screen TVs, jet skis, zip lines, ATVs, huge swimming pools with wave machines, and free iPods for all campers. SC has entomology, long tiring hikes, pointless craft activities, and endless boring lectures about how we all should be helping to save the earth.

    If you’re wondering how FC manages to keep going, it’s not just that the parents of all of its campers are rich and can afford the exorbitant fees. It’s also that FC has perfected the art of “poaching” resources from neighboring camps. FC and SC share a fenceline, after all, and FC resource managers go over after dark and cut down trees in SC’s back 80 for firewood to heat the FC lodges. FC saves on trash collection by just throwing it into a ravine on the western edge of SC’s recreation area. FC’s main waste line also ends at SC’s out-dated swimming pool, if you hadn’t noticed. I’m not telling you anything you didn’t already know, I’m sure. FC has the attorneys to handle any complaints about this situation, not that SC has the nerve to kick up a fuss about it.

    I don’t think it’s much of a mystery why SC has trouble attracting even the few weak, myopic campers that it does pull in. Think about its swell neighbor: what’s not to like about an all-you-can-eat buffet, hypo-allergenic plastic forests with animatronic bears and cougars, double-feature movies every night, and a staff psychiatrist to manage the meds needed to ensure that every little camper’s mood is just right at all times? Or maybe you’d rather crawl around on your knees looking for bugs and gnaw on whole-grain biscuits while somebody strums an off-key guitar and sings “Kumbaya”…? Me, I know which camp I want my kids to go to!

    Reply
  2. Eric A.
    Eric A. says:

    John D. said:
    “FC has the attorneys to handle any complaints about this situation, not that SC has the nerve to kick up a fuss about it.” The entire legal system lives in FC. It is entirely dominated by neoclassical economics. As a law student who is getting a concurrent masters degree in Bioregional Planning and Community Design I can attest to the fact that the legal system is at least a century behind the science. Some folks up in B.C. Canada are starting to bang on the door and I’m going to do my damnedest to bring their ideas south (or I may expatriate…we shall see).

    Check the link: http://www.polisproject.org/projects/greenlegaltheory

    Reply
  3. Angstadt Keller
    Angstadt Keller says:

    Dietz, You state the following:

    “Some things that have value are not priced in markets. We need to establish mechanisms beyond the market to recognize this value.”

    Ok. What are they? I keep reading that “we need to”, but never examples of how it could or should be done. Many of the articles on this site leave open-ended statements like this with the caveat that they will somehow workout once we transition to a steady state economy. I think this is the overarching dilemma that many people, like myself, face when we read into new forms of socio-economic organization–even if they are the most optimal in the face of our obvious limits to economic growth.

    It doesn’t seem that steady state economics challenges the competitive economic model of capitalism–which determines value by the price someone is willing to pay for something they want or need thus creating a race-to-the-bottom scenario for the most privilege socio-economic elites to control. How are we to determine new “mechanisms beyond the market to recognize this value” if we don’t abandon capitalism, or competitive market structures, that only see monetary and capital wealth as valuable?

    I think many people shy away from the so-called “Science Camp”, and the subsequent “ecological economics” that is the inevitable result from aligning oneself with this camp, because they fear that science or “scientism” is pervading individual, social and cultural spheres of experience and reality/meaning making. Yes, our economic modes of production should be based on natural capital and the like, but when it comes to “value” much of that interpretation is subjective and based on a number of aspects to the human experience far beyond just a material basis for our existence.

    Steady State economics ways too heavy on the side of a material basis for our existence. You, and many authors I have read in this field, have never touched on defining, both bioregionally and culturally, what a new theory of value will look like in a steady state mode of production. Yes, it is up to those that inhabit that region, but the way it is constantly mentioned is as if it is a “given” and should not be debated or discussed within this new socio-economic pardigm.

    Reply
  4. Andy B
    Andy B says:

    I really wish that this arguement would be rephrased:

    “When we extract and burn fossil fuels, carbon dioxide accumulates in the atmosphere. A higher concentration of carbon dioxide produces side effects (e.g., increasing temperatures and acidifying oceans) that threaten global climate stability.”

    It is my opinion that the value of climate stability is not apparent to most people. In the United States, we are blessed with so much of our land being ideal for food production. We also get regular rainfall, as opposed to monsoons. We are probably the most agriculturally productive nation, and that is a serious strength. It is in our best interests to have a stable climate in order to continue our success in agriculture.

    Reply
  5. Lee Van Ham
    Lee Van Ham says:

    Rob, I agree that two worldviews compete for our devotion. Thanks for sharing the work you’re doing to delineate them. I’m not so enamored with the names “Fantasy” and “Science,” but I confess to having used a variety of names myself for the same kind of work. Currently, I’m using Multi Earth and One Earth to name the worldviews (http://leevanham.com/blog/). They help me take a kind of confessional stance in that the ecological footprint calculators say I’m using 3+ planets. So I’m a Multi Earther. At the same time, my quest is to be a One Earther. I blog about why Multi Earth living grips us so tightly even when logic and commonsense know this is impossible without coercive taking from others, plus, we see Earth pushing back with ever greater gusto. The religious convictions with which professionals and systems and consumers are attached to neoliberal economics are devilishly difficult to convert.

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Want to join the discussion?
Feel free to contribute!
(No profanity, lewdness, or libel.)

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *