The Steady State Economy Act: Halfway to the Hill?

by Brian Czech
image of capitol hill, through some trees

It’s a long way to the top of Capitol Hill. (Flickr, Creative Commons)

Promulgating the steady state economy via federal legislation has long been a primary goal at CASSE. However, even a primary goal isn’t necessarily pursued from the get-go. Much of the CASSE run thus far has been focused on raising awareness of the need for a steady state economy. Raising such awareness was even higher on the list of goals, because drafting statutory law is of limited use if there is no knowledge of the need for it.

In the midst of the Covid crisis, fifteen years after the establishment of CASSE, we formally commenced developing a steady state economy bill. Covid forced the societal door open for some rethinking of economic policies and activities. We walked through the door and introduced the steady state economy as a post-covid policy vision.

The tentative title of the bill was the “Full and Sustainable Employment Act” (FSEA). We chose this title to emphasize the wholesale replacement of the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 (FEBGA). If the United States has a central economic policy, it’s FEBGA, a pro-growth law hopelessly out of date. (As we like to say at CASSE, growth is sooo 20th century.)

We went so far as to nickname our own developmental bill the “Full Seas Act.” The idea (as elaborated in Supply Shock) was to put an end to the excuse-making metaphor, “a rising tide lifts all boats.” In the 21st century, we’ve run out of material for building more “boats.” We’re running out of room “at sea,” too. A sustainable economy means replacing the boats as they run their life course, not trying to force even more boats—people, businesses, industries—onto the crowded seas.

Our testing of the metaphorical waters was inconclusive, and in 2023 we simply renamed the bill the “Steady State Economy Act.” Putting the phrase “steady state economy” in the very title of the bill makes it crystal clear that we are literally proposing the establishment of a steady state economy in the USA, and not just whistling Dixie.

Findings and Declarations

Perhaps the most important section of a statute is the findings and declarations of Congress. In most substantial laws, the findings and declarations set the stage for the rest of the content. Take, for example, the Endangered Species Act of 1973, in which Congress found and declared that species “have been rendered extinct as a consequence of economic growth and development.” This crucial phrase will forever serve as a reminder that Congress set the precedent long ago in recognizing the ecological threat of economic growth.

For the Steady State Economy Act (SSEA), we had the advantage of having our key findings and declarations—the ones we want Congress to adopt—thought out far in advance. The findings, especially, have taken the form of an online, signable position statement for two decades. Similarly, the declarations stem from the “therefore” clauses of the position statement.

The findings and declarations in the SSEA were first presented under the “Full Seas Act” noted above. Providing them here will reinforce these central pillars of the SSEA, where they will comprise Section 2:

SECTION 2. FINDINGS AND DECLARATIONS.

(a) FINDINGS. The Congress finds that—

(1) Economic growth, as measured with gross domestic product (GDP), requires a growing human population, increasing per capita consumption, or both.

(2) Consistent with the natural sciences, including basic principles of physics and biology, there are limits to economic growth within and among nations.

(3) There is a fundamental conflict between economic growth and environmental protection, including the maintenance of: clean air and water; productive soils; biological diversity; stocks of natural resources including water, timber, fisheries, minerals, and fossil fuels, and; funds of ecosystem services including nutrient cycling, pollination, waste absorption, and carbon sequestration.

(4) A well-maintained, non-degraded environment is the foundation of a productive economy. Therefore, and because of the fundamental conflict between economic growth and environmental protection, there is also a fundamental conflict between economic growth and the long-term maintenance of the economy including jobs, income, and wellbeing.

(5) A well-maintained economy is vital to national defense. Therefore, and because of the fundamental conflict between economic growth and the long-term maintenance of the economy, there is a fundamental conflict between economic growth and national security.

(6) There is abundant environmental and economic evidence that long-term limits to growth have been and are being reached and exceeded in the Nation, other nations, and globally.

(7) There is abundant evidence that perennial fiscal and monetary efforts to stimulate GDP growth are increasingly causing environmental, economic, and social harm while resulting in fewer benefits, with the harm gradually exceeding the benefits.

(b) DECLARATION. The Congress declares that—

(1) It is heretofore the policy of the Nation to undertake a gradual but certain transition from the goal and pursuit of economic growth to the goal and pursuit of a sustainable steady state economy, with stabilized or mildly fluctuating population and per capita consumption as generally indicated, all else being equal, by a mildly fluctuating GDP.

(2) The transition to a steady state economy must be undertaken with every intent and effort to achieve and maintain the full employment of the labor force consistent with environmental protection and other aspects of economic sustainability including a balanced federal budget and the effective control of inflation.

(3) The President, President’s Cabinet, Council of Economic Advisors, Federal Reserve, and federal agency directors will immediately cease and desist from developing strategies and initiatives to grow or stimulate the economy. Existing policies, programs, and projects designed explicitly to grow or stimulate the economy shall not be extended beyond fiscal year 2030 or beyond the designated sunset date, whichever comes later.

(4) The Congressional Research Service, collaborating with the Office of Management and Budget and Council of Economic Advisers, will review and summarize the federal agency mission statements, goals, objectives, policies, programs, and practices designed for GDP growth, producing a Report on Federal Growth Incentives no later than 30 April 2031.

(5) A Commission on Economic Sustainability (“the Commission”) is hereby established to include the Administrator of the Environmental Protection Agency and the Secretaries of Agriculture, Energy, and Commerce, chaired by the Secretary of the Interior, to estimate and monitor environmentally sustainable levels of population and socially optimal levels of GDP. The Commission will produce a Report on Sustainable Population and Optimal GDP no later than 31 August 2031.

(6) The Commission Chair, with counsel of the Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors, Secretary of Commerce, Federal Reserve Chair, and Secretary of the Treasury, drawing on the Report on Federal Growth Incentives and the Report on Sustainable Population and Optimal GDP, and pursuant to the framework provided in subsequent sections herein, will develop and deliver to the President, no later than 31 August 2032, a 25-year Steady-State Transition Plan detailing and scheduling the adjustments, modifications, additions, and deletions necessary to establish a system of government operations most conducive to a steady state economy at an estimated optimal level of GDP.

(7) The President, Cabinet secretaries, and federal agency directors shall not overlook the existence, neglect the enforcement, or underfund the performance of the Clean Air Act, Clean Water Act, Endangered Species Act, National Environmental Policy Act, or any other of the Nation’s environmental laws or regulations on grounds that said laws or regulations may interfere with the workings of the economy or slow the rate of GDP growth.

Progress on the Bill, Procedural and Strategic
Senator Bernie Sanders, looking pensive.

Senator Bernie Sanders, concerned about excessive CEO pay, might like to ponder the Salary Cap Act. (Flickr)

The declarations above are more thorough than in a typical bill, as they are designed to put some procedural meat on the policy bone right from the start. As we develop the bill, some of the particulars laid out in the declarations will be shifted to subsequent sections.

Each significant section we draft is a prospective “feeder bill,” feeding into the broader SSEA. In this way, we hope to establish ties with members of Congress and their staff, as some of these feeder bills will be highly relevant to pre-existing concerns expressed on the Hill. For example, a recurring theme in Congress is the exorbitant pay of billionaire CEOs. Our Salary Cap Act ought to resonate with every politician who expresses a sincere concern about excessive income.

The Salary Cap Act is a good example of a bill that can unify those concerned especially with sustainability (thus far a small group including CASSE) and those concerned primarily with economic fairness (a larger number of individuals and organizations). Any feeder bill that connects with pre-existing concerns of members of Congress will help us educate those same members on limits to growth as well, and the need for a steady state economy. That helps us hew to our 501(c)(3) status as an educational non-profit organization with only limited lobbying clearance.

Below is the draft SSEA table of contents, provided only to the Section level. A more complete outline of the bill includes subsidiary sections, along with hyperlinks to a handful of feeder bills we’ve drafted thus far.

 

Section 1. Short Title; Table of Contents.
Section 2. Findings and Declarations.
Section 3. Definitions.
Section 4. Executive Adoption of Steady-State Goals.
Section 5. Fiscal Policy.
Section 6. Monetary Policy.
Section 7. Sustainable Immigration.
Section 8. Trade and Capital Mobility.
Section 9. Labor and Income.
Section 10. Housing and Transportation.
Section 11. Caps And Tradeable Permits.
Section 12. Economic Incentives.
Section 13. Prohibitions.
Section 14. Penalties and Enforcement.

 

This feeder bill approach won’t be without its challenges. Developing a complete collection of feeder bills doesn’t mean we will be able to simply splice them together to produce the SSEA. Rather, we’ll need to consolidate various components and pay careful attention to problems of redundancy or inconsistency. For example, most of our feeder bills will include a Definitions section. Those will be removed from their immediate context and compiled into a comprehensive Definitions section for the full SSEA. This type of work will require impeccable attention to detail, similar to the work performed by the Office of the Law Revision Counsel, the codifiers of statutory law. We are prepared to do this type of work in-house, slowly but surely.

As a small non-profit organization, we don’t have the resources to hire attorneys with copious legislative experience. However, we do have one full-time staffer devoted to the SSEA: Policy Specialist Daniel Wortel-London, who we hired in May, 2023. He has a Ph.D. from New York University and a keen interest in economic policy. Since signing on with CASSE, he has studied the canons of statutory construction and elements of style in drafting legislation. He assists with the development of feeder bills and monthly columns at the Steady State Herald, which are reviewed and fleshed out in-house.

As we develop more of the SSEA, we’ll be welcoming the help of individuals and organizations with an interest in the act as a whole or in particular feeder bills. A glance at the table of contents above, or further inspection of the deeper outline, should help third parties decide if they are interested in assessing, helping with, or funding the work. Potential collaborators should also consider some of the core policy principles we adhere to.

Policy Design Principles, Old and New

Each of our SSEA feeder bills follows the basic “SATG” model of public policy developed by political scientists Anne Schneider and Helen Ingram. The bill we draft is the statement (S) of policy, in which we identify the agent or agencies (A) charged with administering the policy. These agencies monitor and oversee actions by a particular “target” or targets (T) in order to fulfill the goal or goals (G) of the policy. If any of these elements cannot be readily identified in a bill, the design is flawed and the bill needs more work.

For example, our Luxury Cap Act (S) charges the Secretary of the Treasury (A) with administering a set of caps and taxes on luxury goods and services. This disincentivizes producers and consumers (T) from producing and consuming luxury goods and services, thereby lessening the nation’s ecological footprint, which is the policy goal (G).

In constructing the SSEA and prioritizing feeder bills, we draw from our long-running list of our top 15 policy recommendations. We also adhere to the policy principles outlined in the Daly and Farley (2010) textbook, Ecological Economics. Some of the policies we develop—such as the Salary Cap Act—come directly from the policy proposals provided in Supply Shock (now published by the Steady State Press).

image fo the USGS logo, which says "science for a changing world" under the USGS.

In a changing world, and pursuant to the “no net gain in bureaucracy” principle, many USGS ecologists would be reassigned to biocapacity and ecological footprint mapping. (USGS).

We have also adopted a few principles along the way, including one we call “no net gain in bureaucracy.” Rather than designate new agencies (A) entailing the hiring of thousands more civil servants, we lean on existing agencies for their expertise in everything from ecological footprint calculation to money supply management. The experts in these agencies are themselves a type of target (T); their approach and activities will change substantially upon passage of the SSEA.

For example, since FEBGA was passed in 1978, the Federal Reserve has had essentially a two-part mission: full employment (which they pursue via “rising tide lifts all boats”) and stabilized prices (which they have interpreted as low but steady inflation rates.) Pursuant to the SSEA, the Fed will be out of the growth business and concerned almost exclusively with minimizing inflation by prudently managing the money supply in close concert with the Department of the Treasury. Economists at the Fed will still be the most capable experts for doing that, even with (or especially with) the tightened mission.

The ”no net gain in bureaucracy” principle helps us adhere to another steady-state policy principle: “No net gain in expenditure.” Spending our way to sustainability leads us straight into the teeth of the “trophic conundrum,” whereby it costs an environmental impact to generate real money for new government programs and incentives. This is why you’ll find a greater degree of “prohibitive policy” in our work than in the proposals of those who favor a market-oriented or grant-providing approach toward steady-state behavior.

That brings us to one more principle worth noting: Political feasibility is to be sought while developing policy, not used as an excuse to eschew policy development. We wouldn’t be working on the SSEA if we didn’t think it would garner political feasibility in the coming decades of ecological unravelling, economic crisis, national insecurity and international instability. Compelling policy work and political feasibility will come hand-in-hand.

So, are we half way to Capitol Hill with the SSEA? Well, not in terms of the percentage of material that needs to be drafted. On the other hand, we’ve laid the foundation and assembled some of the most crucial expertise, and that is some of the most time-consuming work. So, in that sense, perhaps we are halfway indeed!

Brian Czech is CASSE’s Executive Director.

blank

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
10 replies
  1. David Bergman
    David Bergman says:

    My fear is that references to stabilized population will be exploited and turned into accusations of government population control. (Look at how the 15-minute city concept has been twisted.) Plus, how do we deal with the reality of an increasing world population? Does a stabilized population goal become a further rationalization by others for immigration bashing?

    Our biggest barrier, in my opinion, is public perception. No politician (well, almost none) is going to want to be labeled anti-growth (degrowth is a terrible term) or in favor of population control, even if that’s not actually what is meant.

    I’m not saying any of the Act is wrong, but we have to anticipate how it will be purposely mischaracterized.

    Reply
  2. Geoffrey Matthews
    Geoffrey Matthews says:

    Excellent Brian. In my opinion David has identified the major barrier, public awareness. A real challenge, because political awareness follows public awareness.
    Re degrowth I have started to use the word “rescaling”. Daly and Farley’s book “Ecological economics, principals and applications” has several excellent references and explanations re scale. During a meeting at the World Bank I remember Herman saying that “scale is everything”.
    Re population and immigration, I like to think that public awareness also leads to the issue of scale, which will encourage the public to think seriously about this issue. In that way no need to legislate.

    Reply
    • Brian Czech
      Brian Czech says:

      Thank you Geoffrey. I personally appreciate the lingo of “re-scaling.” Similarly “sustainable scale,” straight out of the Dalyist school of ecological economics. I fondly recall “The Scale Project” of the Santa-Barbara Family Foundation.

      In retrospect, though, I think building upon the concept of sustainable scale with copious use of “scale” phraseology won’t get us far out of a sort of sustainability intelligentsia. The phraseology is rife with “need to explain” in order to avoid conflation with more vernacular uses of the term “scale.”

      This is the great advantage of the degrowth movement: “Degrowth” fits all the linguistic criteria for effective sloganeering and branding. Yet I still think “steady state economy” is not only a powerful concept but a potent linguistic and rhetorical label. We continue to run with it, as growing awareness about limits to growth will lead to public understanding that the steady state economy is the sustainable alternative: to growth and to degrowth.

      Reply
    • Brian Czech
      Brian Czech says:

      Degrowth as a movement is a big tent and you might consider CASSE at the conceptual center of it. Remember, the steady state economy is the sustainable alternative to growth — and to degrowth. CASSE has a rich history with the degrowth movement dating back to its beginnings.

      At CASSE, we’ve long been for temporary degrowth toward a durable steady state economy in the rich countries; likewise temporary growth toward a durable steady state economy in poverty-stricken countries. You’ll find that stated clearly in the CASSE position on economic growth. We call the requisite international political dynamics “steady statesmanship” in international diplomacy.

      That said, away from the conceptual middle of the tent, the political degrowth movement has come to mean a lot of things to a lot of people. More on that for another time, maybe.

      Meanwhile, the focus of the article above is hard-core public policy leading toward a steady state economy in the United States. The Steady State Economy Act will include a section on steady statesmanship in international diplomacy; some degrowth in action, as it were.

      Reply
  3. Len Verwey
    Len Verwey says:

    Thank you.

    As you’ll know, in principle one could get GDP growth that is significantly less natural resource intensive and focus on this sort of growth. Service sectors etc. I don’t buy this, and I’m sure CASSE doesnt either, but it may be worth adding some phrasing that anticipates this argument.

    For example:

    (2) Consistent with the natural sciences, including basic principles of physics and biology, there are limits to economic growth within and among nations for any feasible / viable combination of natural, human and financial resources in production.

    Reply
    • Brian Czech
      Brian Czech says:

      Thank you Len. You hit the nail on the head. And you’re right, CASSE doesn’t buy the decoupling, “green growth” nonsense for a millisecond. We never have. Our rejection of decoupled green growth is one of the original impetuses for CASSE’s establishment in 2003.

      By the way, our central counter-argument to the decoupling fallacy has evolved into the trophic theory of money:

      https://tinyurl.com/49dxud6c

      But particularly to your point about “service sectors,” and for a much quicker read, we find it easy to refute what we call the “self-sufficient services fallacy:”

      https://tinyurl.com/yj3zw3jz

      As for adding another clause to the Steady State Economy Act, I do believe we have these principles covered in the Findings and Declarations (and certainly in the CASSE position on economic growth at https://www.steadystate.org/act/sign-the-position/read-the-position-statement/ ). But it’s always a challenge; you can’t include nuanced theses—very little jargon either—in online petitions or in federal legislation.

      Reply
    • Philip Lawn
      Philip Lawn says:

      The ‘shift to services’ is another ‘green growth’ myth. It overlooks the trophic structure of economies, which consists of the primary trophic level (agriculture and resource extraction), the secondary trophic level (manufacturing), and the tertiary trophic level (services). The majority of the output of the primary trophic level becomes the input of the secondary trophic level. Ditto the secondary to the tertiary trophic level. You can’t increase the physical scale of the tertiary trophic level by reducing the physical scale of the primary and secondary trophic levels. By increasing the use value (quality) of what we produce at the secondary tertiary trophic level, we might be able to reduce the output generated at this trophic level to provide a given level of welfare benefits at the tertiary trophic level, but that’s not the substitution of tertiary trophic level output for secondary trophic level output. There will also be limits to doing this.

      Evidence? If shifting to services reduces the environmental impact of a growing economy, why is it that over the last fifty years, as services as a share of GDP has increased from around 55% to 70-80% in most wealthy nations, the quantity of resources used/wastes generated in these countries has increased? Do we have to wait until the share rises to 95% of GDP until the impact declines?

      In addition, poor nations, where services as a share of GDP is currently around 50-60%, have a smaller per capita rate of resource use/waste generation than rich countries. Shouldn’t it be higher? How do the green growth advocates explain that? They can’t! Ultimately, scale (how much we produce) matters more than how we produce stuff, as important as the latter is. Growth of the human niche (us and our stuff) is the real killer of the planet – a cancer of the Earth.

      Reply
  4. Mark Cramer
    Mark Cramer says:

    I find it painful that beautiful policy ideas, as in Brian’s article, gain little traction in the public.There are counter-logics about the word “degrowth”. Here in France, every month I find 7 or 8 elitist or far-right politicians expressing their repudiation of “décroissance”. The fact that they need to make such repudiations says that the word & ideas behind it have gained some traction. My current failure as an activist to make an impact for CASSE here in France is partly a question of timing. Most potential degrowth activists have a priority of opposing the ongoing bloody wars and trying to stop them, and in the context of death and destruction, it is hard to focus a discussion on ecology. The irony is that the military-industrial complex that profits from these wars is at once boosting GDP and causing ecological catastrophes.

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Want to join the discussion?
Feel free to contribute!
(No profanity, lewdness, or libel.)

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *